There are different types of externalities. The definition above already suggests that they can be either positive or negative. Additionally, there is another (and maybe less familiar) distinction which should be made here: Both positive and negative externalities can arise on the productionor on the consumption side.
In the following paragraphs we will look at the different types of externalities in more detail.
Positive externalities
Economic activities that have positive effects on unrelated third parties are considered positive externalities. As we learned above, they may be present in the form of production or consumption externalities.Positive production externalities are positive effects that originate during the production process of an economic actor. An example of this could be an orchard placed next to a beehive. In this situation both the farmer and the beekeeper benefit from each other, even though neither of them has considered the other one's needs in his decision-making.
Positive production externality
This can be illustrated by comparing social cost and social benefit based on a supply and demand diagram. In this case, individual demand (D) is equal to social benefit (SB) since there are no externalities on the consumption side. However social cost (SC) is lower than individual supply (S) because there is an external benefit (EB) that is not included in the individual supply curve. As a result the market equilibrium (E*) is different from the optimal market situation (O*) and there is an undersupply of both orchards and beehives.Positive consumption externalities are positive effects on third parties that originate from the consumption of a good or service. A possible example could be your neighbor’s flower garden. She most likely cultivates the plants solely for her own pleasure, yet you can still enjoy the beauty of the flowers whenever you walk by.
Positive consumption externality
Again, this can be illustrated by comparing social cost and social benefit. In this case however, the individual demand curve (D) lies below the social benefit curve (SB) because the external benefit (the beauty of the flowers) is not included in the neighbor's demand curve. The social cost (SC) on the other hand is equal to the individual supply (S) because there are no externalities on the production side. Like in the first illustration the market equilibrium (E*) is different from the optimal market situation (O*) and as a result there is an undersupply of flowers. What is different from the previous illustration though, the optimal price (p2) in this example is higher than the equilibrium price (p1).Generally speaking, for positive externalities the overall benefit to society is higher than the one that is taken into account by the actors during their decision-making process. This results in an undersupply of beneficial products (or activities) for society. In order to correct these market failures it is important to know whether the externality arises from the production or the consumption side, since this affects the desired optimal market equilibrium.
Negative externalities
Analogous to the previous paragraphs, negative externalities are economic activities that have negative effects on unrelated third parties. They can be divided further into production and consumption externalities.Negative production externalities are negative effects that originate during the production process of an economic actor. The most common example of this kind of externality is the pollution caused by a firm during the production of their goods. Pollution affects the entire population, however as long as companies are not held accountable for their activities, they have no incentive to reduce their economic impact (since that would be more expensive).
Negative production externality
To illustrate this, we shall compare social cost and social benefit again. Similar to the positive externality example, individual demand (D) represents social benefit (SB). The social cost curve (SC) in this case however is higher than the individual supply curve (S) because of the external cost (EC) that is not included in the firms supply decision. As a result the market equilibrium (E*) is different from the optimal market situation (O*) and there is an oversupply of harmful behavior. In this example the optimal price of the good (p2) is higher than its actual market price (p1).
Negative consumption externalities are negative effects that arise during the consumption of a good or service. To give an example, we can revisit your neighbor. If she likes to play loud music in the middle of the night, a negative externality on your part could be sleep deprivation. Once again, she may not take this into account since the consequences do not directly affect her.
Negative consumption externality
In this case, the individual demand curve (D) lies above the social benefit curve (SB) because of the external cost (your sleep deprivation) that is not included in the neighbor's demand curve. The social cost curve (SC) on the other hand is equal to the individual supply (S), because there are no externalities on the production side. Again, the market equilibrium (E*) is different from the optimal market situation (O*) and as a result there is an oversupply of loud music. For this example the optimal price of the good (p2) is lower than its actual market price (p1).